Showing posts with label modern money theory. Show all posts
Showing posts with label modern money theory. Show all posts

Sunday, January 7, 2018

Breaching the fiscal deficit target: what’s the big deal?


On February 1, 2017, the big news dominating the headlines was the fiscal deficit target number: 3.2% of GDP.  It seemed the government was well on track with experts expressing their satisfaction over the budget’s focus on fiscal consolidation and the hope that it would comply with the FRBM target of 3% of GDP by 2018-19.  For once, even rating agencies like Standard & Poor and Moody’s “lauded India’s commitment to improve fiscal performance, but said a rating upgrade is still sometime away.”[1]

And then some eleven months later the outcome emerging is something quite different; the government is likely to breach its 3.2% fiscal deficit target stoking “fiscal worries”[2], a dreaded disease that inflicts most mainstream macroeconomists and experts.  Before you get drowned in all the numbers being thrown at you in lakhs of crores and trillions, I attempt to give readers a heterodox economics view drawing upon the tenets of Modern Money Theory (MMT) that allays many unnecessary fears about the fiscal deficit and instead shift focus to what should be the center of discussion.

Fiscal policy consists of two elements; government expenditure and taxes.  The first part of the budget is a statement of government expenditure decided upon at the beginning of the financial year.  Why does the government need to spend?  To achieve its political, economic and social objectives, the government must transfer real resources from the private sector to itself.  It does this by “spending” or literally “buying” goods and services from the private sector using its money or IOUs (I Owe You).  This leads to the most important question in MMT; why does the private sector accept the government’s money or IOUs?  To pay taxes; the private sector must discharge its tax obligations to the state only in the IOUs issued by the government or what we call as legal tender.  Taxes drive (state) money.  This is a critical feature of modern fiat money; the state does not need our money to spend.  Instead, we need the state’s money – that is created when it spends – to discharge our tax obligations to it.

But there is another crucial reason for imposition of taxes – controlling inflation[3] – which brings us to the second part of the budget. When the government spends its money into the economy, more of it will be available with the private sector which may drive up demand for goods and services, resulting in rising price levels or inflation.  To prevent this taxes are imposed on private sector entities in order to drain the economy of excess money injected through government spending.  But the government does not fix the amount of taxes that has to be paid by private agents.  For example, it cannot stipulate that a grocery store will have to pay Rs.100,000 in taxes every year.  What if sales of the grocery store falls drastically during the year?  The government therefore fixes the tax rate as a percentage of incomes, profit or sales.  Ideally income and corporate taxes are considered the most fair especially with progressive rates as well as non-distortionary (in terms of its low impact on relative prices).

Unfortunately, in a country like India where the tax base is abysmally narrow it becomes difficult to drain out government money from this small section of people without recourse to high tax rates – which then has a significant negative impact on incentives.  Instead, the government must resort to indirect taxes – like GST – which obviously has a wider tax base but is unfortunately regressive in its impact on the poor.  But that’s a compromise we have to live with perhaps partial offsetting by a lower tax rate on essential goods and services.

As the economy progresses through the year, the government’s policies as well as a multitude of other factors from private sector sentiments to international trends determines output produced, sales, incomes and profits that directly influence actual tax collections.  Unfortunately, when the economy does not perform as expected, tax collections turn out to be lower too while the deficit widens for any given amount of government expenditure undertaken.  This property of fiscal policy is called an “automatic stabilizer”; the deficit widens during times of poor economic growth and narrows when growth is strong.

At this point, let me digress briefly into what constitutes state money or its IOUs.  When the government buys goods and services from the private sector, your account in a commercial bank will be credited with a certain amount; these are simply tokens or numbers in the books of accounts of all stakeholders.  But the government does not do this transaction directly; instead, its banker (the central bank or the Reserve Bank of India) will credit “reserve money” into the account of the commercial bank which then credits your account with this sum.  This reserve money is the liability of the central bank or what it owes to the private sector.  If the private sector entity wants cash, the “reserve money” is printed on pieces of paper and delivered through the commercial bank so that it is easily exchangeable by private sector agents for transactions between themselves.  What about taxes?  Taxes must be remitted back to the government’s account at the central bank only with “reserve money” or “cash” (printed slips of reserve money).  When a private sector entity pays taxes the commercial bank debits its account and then transfers the same amount of reserve money (which it had earlier received when the government undertook spending) back to the central bank.  Government spending creates reserve money, taxes destroy the same. There is nothing physical about this money; it is essentially a grand bookkeeping system.

In the good ol’ days, the government could ask the central bank to credit its account with as much reserve money it wanted it to in exchange for government promises to pay back later or what is called, government securities or bonds.  The government/central bank would also sell these bonds to the public (and even promise to pay them interest on them) to mop up excess state money floating around in the private sector (untaxed spending) to prevent inflation.  These sale of bonds accumulated over time becomes the infamous and much feared public debt – what we, however, often fail to realize is that the other side of public debt is private sector (financial) assets.  Government bonds are the safest income yielding security that the private sector can hold – would we feel safe parking all our wealth in physical assets (land or gold) or in private sector financial assets (equity shares or commercial paper of companies)?  Obviously not; every individual would aspire that at least a part of his/her wealth be held in government securities or financial assets not backed by any physical asset (the latter could depreciate or at any time, turn bad).  In fact, the curtailing of public debt would force the private sector to save in private sector financial assets – the insecurity may even force the savings rate up and cause a contraction in consumption spending.

Does the government need to borrow in order to spend?  Obviously not; it could simply raise taxes or let inflation accelerate.  Moreover, the fact that the government does not need to borrow before it spends can easily be seen from the fact that bonds must be purchased from the government in exchange for reserve money only.  Just like taxes, spending (injection of reserve money) must precede bond issues (draining of reserve money).

Ever since the rise of neoliberal macroeconomics in the 1980s that sought to restrict the influence of the state in the free market system, fiscal policy was “proven” impotent.  The quantifiable target of government intrusion was the fiscal deficit and it had to be curtailed.  Governments were convinced (or perhaps forced to under the influence of structural adjustment programs of the IMF) that fiscal policy more than anything caused accelerating inflation that threw the free market system out of gear.  Low and stable inflation was made the center of macroeconomic policy so that market forces would propel the economy to full employment. For this, fiscal deficits had to be restricted and if not, “independent central banks” (under the charge of a professional economist) were given the power to set interest rates to mitigate the dangers of rising inflation from fiscal profligacy.  Rating agencies that imbibed and propagated this neoliberal worldview kept nation-states in-check and against deviating from this model.  After all, a de-rating could mean lower foreign exchange inflows (from FDI, ECB and FII flows) and a balance of payments crisis.

A further offshoot of neoliberal macroeconomics was pressure of governments to impose constrains on themselves – like the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM) Act of 2003 – whereby the government must not let the fiscal deficit rise above 3% of GDP and more importantly, it cannot engage in “deficit financing”.  This means that unlike the good ol’ days the government can no longer borrow or get an overdraft from the RBI but has instead to borrow in the market (from the private sector) before it spends. In other words, there must be sufficient money in the government’s account at the central bank before it signs cheques on the private sector.

Does this self-imposed constraint by the government really mean that the government cannot increase its expenditure if required?  Not really; a system[4] Primary Dealers (PDs) and Bank-PDs has been put in place wherein governments will be able to obtain the required amount through mandatory participation of these entities in the bond auctions.  The central bank, however, stands by to provide reserve money to PDs to meet their obligations.  In fact, it can be shown that “the end result is exactly the same as if the central bank had bought directly from the Treasury.” (Tymoigne 2014[5]).

So what I have attempted to show here is that the fiscal deficit or public debt target number is really not important; it cannot and must not be the objective of macroeconomic policy.  All this, however, does not mean there is no big deal on account of the widening fiscal deficit. In fact, there is a critical question that needs to be posed; what went wrong with government policies that brought down the growth rate sharply? And this even as the world is witnessing a kind of economic boom with robust growth, low unemployment and low inflation (although poor real wage growth).  Have the twin shocks of demonetization and GST implementation derailed the economy? Or is the unresolved NPA problem along with low private sector business sentiment suppressing growth?

Deflection from these questions into breaching of fiscal deficit target numbers is fraught with a greater danger – the imposition (with a little encouragement from rating agencies) of austerity measures – which as MMTers have long argued, is bound to take the country down a spiraling path – lower government spending, lower GDP growth, lower tax collections, widening fiscal deficits and therefore the need for even greater austerity!




[3] Taxes are also used to achieve other objectives; sectoral allocation of resources, curb negative externalities, redistribution of income and wealth, etc.  In this article, we consider the purely financial aspect of taxes.
[4] Master Circular – Operational Guidelines for Primary Dealers, Reserve Bank of India, July 1, 2015, https://www.rbi.org.in/scripts/BS_ViewMasCirculardetails.aspx?id=9841#8
[5] Éric Tymoigne, Modern Money Theory and Interrelations between the Treasury and the Central
Bank: The Case of the United States, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper # 788, March 2014, http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download;jsessionid=89DEA9B2158162AA06 B4840477ABF6D8?doi=10.1.1.640.4425&rep=rep1&type=pdf  

Sunday, October 2, 2016

My latest research from a heterodox macroeconomics perspective

Earlier this year, I had undertaken to carry out a few country studies from a heterodox macroeconomic perspective.  Three of them have now been published:
  1. China’s macroeconomic policy options: a sectoral financial balances approach,Studies in Business & Economics, 2016, 11(1): 152-163.

     
  2. Cracks in BRICs: a sectoral financial balances analysis and implications for macroeconomic policy, Theoretical and Applied Economics, 23(3), Autumn: 53-78.

     
  3. Can a country really go broke? Deconstructing Saudi Arabia’s macroeconomic crisis, Real World Economics Review, Issue 76, September 2016: 75-94.


    The above articles can be read at:



    http://Independent.academia.edu/SashiSivramkrishna
Looking forward to some critical comments.

Friday, September 25, 2015

Aggregate demand, corporate debt and deleveraging

Here are a couple of articles which indicate the consequences of a slack in aggregate demand on corporate debt and the growing need for companies to deleverage debt through asset sales.  We can notice this trend not just in India but also in China.

http://www.livemint.com/Companies/JBn41JpbNPdPBxzOb2FzIO/LT-to-sell-assets-dilute-stake-in-noncore-businesses-AM.html

http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/opinion/editorial/taking-a-haircut/article7678161.ece

Does the government need to step in and increase infrastructure spending?  Can we hold on to "austerity" and worry about fiscal deficit targets?  How do we know that infrastructure projects will not be underutilized (like ghost towns in China)?

These are questions to ponder over.


Friday, May 22, 2015

The general drift of neoliberalism

Two headlines caught my attention today; from these we get a clear picture of the general drift of neoliberalism.   The Times of India (see link below) declared:

SOCIOECONOMICS: BIG TALK, TIGHT FIST
Funds cuts pinch edu & health schemes

Slashing the education budget and keeping the outlay on health static in Modi government's first Budget was seemingly based on the sound logic of the Finance Commission giving bigger share of taxes to states.

But three months later, harsh reality has sunk in. Mid-Day Meal (MDM) cooks, anganwadi workers and Mahila Samakhya workers have hit the streets and state governments are feeling the heat ….


The other headlines that was an interesting contrast to this was in the Livemint.

Industries call on Modi to spend Rs.1 trillion (Rs.100,000 crore) to boost economy

… At the top of India Inc.’s wish list are investments in infrastructure, simplification of rules for acquiring land and implementation of a proposed national sales tax. Executives say the government should take the lead in financing new roads and public projects to give the maximum boost to Asia’s third- biggest economy.

V.S. Parthasarathy, group chief financial officer at Mahindra and Mahindra Ltd, suggests Modi make a dramatic move by investing as much as Rs.1 trillion ($16 billion) on infrastructure in the next six months. That would provide the country with tangible assets, signal confidence in the future and inject cash that would cascade through the broader economy …


So is industry really against spending and deficits per se or does it prefer one kind of spending to another?  And the government?  Let’s be clear.



Friday, May 15, 2015

MMT cautions us against reacting to such headlines

Fed said to have emergency plan to intervene if U.S. defaulted on debt

WASHINGTON 


Reuters, Markets Mon May 11, 2015 6:59pm EDT




RICARDIAN EQUIVALENCE: IT SOUNDS SO PROFOUND IT MUST BE TRUE


In a recent piece, Tarun Ramadorai of the Said School of Business, Oxford University, has evoked upon Ricardian Equivalence (RE) to base his argument for optimal debt management.

Does economic theory offer any guidance about the optimal management of government debt?
One of the fundamental concepts in thinking about government debt is Ricardian Equivalence. David Ricardo posited in the 1800s that since debt must eventually be repaid by governments, it is essentially equivalent to future taxation (and will be perceived as such by taxpayers). Essentially all work in economics on public debt management relies on this concept in one way or another.
If debt and future tax policy are two sides of the same coin, the obvious step is to think through the role of debt in the context of sensible tax policy. 


His article can be found at:

http://www.livemint.com/Opinion/RJDJPFZ7X65Kqa4DlbSZPK/Public-debt-management-back-to-school.html


Without examining what he says about this, it is interesting to see how economists evoke RE to build upon their arguments.  RE simply does not hold true in a world of fiat currency.  Ricardo's principle perhaps held true in a world of commodity currency but economists seem indifferent to this changed reality.

The fundamental flaw with RE have been examined in this piece by Auerback and should be read.

https://www.creditwritedowns.com/2010/07/why-ricardian-equivalence-is-nonsense.html

But what interests me is how economic jargon and hi-sounding terms like RE find their way into popular discourse and are swallowed by general readers.








Wednesday, May 13, 2015

Decentring Fiscal Deficit Target Numbers

You can find my article in the Economic & Political Weekly of 09-05-2015.  Or follow this link:

independent.academia.edu/SashiSivramkrishna

The article questions the obsession with fiscal deficit traget numbers like 3.1% of GDP or 3.6% or 3.9%. Does it really matter?  Should it be the goal of macroeconomic policy??




Friday, February 6, 2015

This is what MMT is weary about ....

Union Budget 2015: FM Arun Jaitley hints at more cuts in spending
Ahead of the Budget 2015-16 to be unveiled later this month, Jaitley hinted at a stable tax regime, saying that 'no unfair effort' will be made by states and the Centre to mop up revenues.

Having already crossed the fiscal deficit target in November, Finance Minister Arun Jaitley today hinted at more cuts in spending so as to contain it within limits for the current fiscal, saying he does not believe in living on borrowed money.

"We're trying to rationalise expenditure as far as the government is concerned because we do not want the government to live on borrowed money indefinitely," he told a gathering of industrialists and planners here via video conferencing.

"The whole concept of spending beyond your means and leaving the next generation in debt to repay what we are overspending today is never prudent fiscal policy," he said. The additionally hinted spending cuts would be over and above 10 percent that the government has already announced to meet the budgeted 4.1 percent fiscal deficit target which was crossed in November itself -- four months ahead of the end of the financial year on March 31. 

…..




Saturday, October 25, 2014

German austerity: will the euro zone break up?

Anyone familiar with MMT would see the misery Germany is heading towards.  Even worse it will take with it the rest of Europe.  Excerpts below from an article that appeared in the Livemint today (25 October 2014) (http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/10/24/uk-eu-summit-idUKKCN0ID0VF20141024) clearly highlights the fears that many modern money theorists have been warning us about.  What is surprising is that there is no popular political voices coming from Germany that make an MMT argument against German austerity.

Stagnating euro zone seeks German shift
BY FRANCESCO GUARASCIO AND ROBIN EMMOTT

After the bloc's revival came to a halt in the second quarter, France and Italy want to shift course away from the spending cuts that marked the bloc's response to the 2009-2012 crisis Germany says debt discipline must continue.

Seated around a large oval table in the EU summit's red marble building, Merkel said no country with a national debt greater than its economic output should be borrowing more, diplomats said.

According to people in the room, Merkel said record low interest rates gave the euro zone "room to breathe" and that a mix of private investment, fiscal discipline and openness to fast-growing Asian economies was the way forward.
The debate is complicated by EU rules that seek to keep country's public finances in order and Germany's promise to balance its books next year for the first time since 1969.

Wednesday, October 22, 2014

How mainstream macroeconomics thinking finds its way into popular discourse.

Two excerpts from articles that appeared in the Livemint of 20 October 2014 show how the need to achieve a fiscal deficit target is becoming an end in itself.  More than the fiscal deficit number per se the debate needs to focus on the real effects of subsidies in distorting resource allocation (if that is so) and the unproductive expenditure of the government that fails to ease supply side constraints and raise productivity.  There is surely space for an MMT perspective on these issues.

Is the centre finally cracking down on subsidies?
Decisions on diesel prices and cooking gas subsidy will help meet centre’s fiscal deficit target of 4.1% of GDP

Remya Nair
The move will also enable the government to meet its fiscal deficit target of 4.1% of gross domestic product (GDP), even after taking into account the expected shortfall in revenue collections.
A Union cabinet minister, who did not wish to be identified, pointed out that the government cannot afford to continue with the current subsidy regime. “There are no freebies. We cannot afford to bankrupt the state exchequer,” the minister said, signalling the central government’s intent to overhaul the subsidy regime.

What it takes to make in India
The first and most important condition for manufacturing success in India is to have a low inflation regime

Narayan Ramachandran 

The first task in ensuring a low inflation environment is to eliminate the primary deficit. This deficit is the difference between the total revenue and total expenditure of the government with debt payments netted out of the calculation. India must begin to deliver upon both a primary and fiscal deficit target as measures of fiscal consolidation in its annual budget. The elimination of the primary deficit and a reduction in the fiscal deficit (to say 2.5% of GDP) will ensure that we live within our means each year, do not increase the stock of debt and crowd out less capital from the productive economy.




Friday, September 19, 2014

IMF, India's fiscal deficits and the need to question the obvious

I just read a news report from Business Today (19-Sept-2014) that speaks of the IMF asking the RBI to raise interest rates.  The infatuation over fiscal deficits as being the most serious problem that Indian macroeconomic policy needs to address runs throughout the article.  But there were also some contradictions that I came across, reading between the lines.  Here are some statements from the article that I want to highlight:

"...IMF said the government needed to take more steps to reduce stubbornly high inflation and the large fiscal deficit."

"The IMF said removing supply bottlenecks would lead to more sustainable growth. It also called for increasing public spending on infrastructure to ease supply bottlenecks and support economic development."

"While lauding the new government's emphasis on fiscal consolidation, it said "the quality and durability of the consolidation remain a cause of concern.""

"The government proposes to bring down the fiscal deficit to 4.1 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP) in current year from 4.5 per cent last fiscal ... fiscal deficit has to be brought down to three per cent of the GDP by 2016-17."

On the one hand the IMF wants to cut the fiscal deficit while at the same time they want an increase in public spending on infrastructure.  When they say the quality of the deficit is important, what do they mean?  What are the items that the government should cut spending on?

Also, like MMT warns us, why this concern about fiscal deficit numbers like 4.1% and 3% of GDP?  Will achieving these numbers solve India's macroeconomic problems?

It's time for MMTers to question what is now being seen as obvious in India.



Follow this link to read the article in Business Today:

http://businesstoday.intoday.in/story/rbi-should-raise-policy-rates-to-cut-inflation-imf-g20-cairn/1/210504.html








My book entitled, "In Search of Stability:  Economics of Money, History of the Rupee" should be out soon.  As the title suggests, I have traced the history of the rupee from 1542 to 1971 and added an epilogue which extends the study up to present times,  All this is done from a positive economics standpoint.  The book, however, does not take a critical stand on the colonial regime by asking what would have happened if things had been different; say, for instance, if India would have been better off had we moved on to a gold standard instead of the gold exchange standard in the late 19th century.  Rather we explore what the gold exchange standard was and its implications of price and exchange rate stability for India.  With this understanding, students and economic historians could pose more critical questions for further study.  The book has been accepted for publication by Manohar Book Publishers, New Delhi, India.

After completing the book I was keen to further explore the more recent history of the rupee, specifically post-1971.  It is while to trying to find a suitable theoretical framework within which I could place my study that I came across Modern Money Theory or MMT.  Over the last few months I have gone through several books, blogs and videos by the main proponents of MMT.  It's not only fascinating but has opened up a whole new world for me.  I had studied Keynesian macroeoconomics during my M.A. at Bombay (now Mumbai) University but was then exposed to a completely different macroeconomics at Cornell while doing my Ph.D.; if I recollect rightly it was dynamic optimization (micro was supposedly static optimization).  Confused about what I was really learning from all those models, my interests shifted altogether to political economy.  Luckily for me I got back to teaching Macroeconomics 101 to management students in India and have been able to hold on to simple Keynesian theory.

My interest in the economic history of the rupee and Keynesian macroeconomics somehow comes together when I read through the literature on MMT.  As I mentioned, it has opened a new window for me to understand fiscal and monetary policies in India today.

I will share things that I come across from sources including newspapers, magazines and TV that I think are important and need a re-look.  I do not intend to make any theoretical contribution to MMT right now at least; those interested could Google "modern money theory" and easily find material from the masters. I think there is a dire need of MMT for India; this is where I hope to make some contribution.