Showing posts with label austerity. Show all posts
Showing posts with label austerity. Show all posts

Sunday, January 7, 2018

Breaching the fiscal deficit target: what’s the big deal?


On February 1, 2017, the big news dominating the headlines was the fiscal deficit target number: 3.2% of GDP.  It seemed the government was well on track with experts expressing their satisfaction over the budget’s focus on fiscal consolidation and the hope that it would comply with the FRBM target of 3% of GDP by 2018-19.  For once, even rating agencies like Standard & Poor and Moody’s “lauded India’s commitment to improve fiscal performance, but said a rating upgrade is still sometime away.”[1]

And then some eleven months later the outcome emerging is something quite different; the government is likely to breach its 3.2% fiscal deficit target stoking “fiscal worries”[2], a dreaded disease that inflicts most mainstream macroeconomists and experts.  Before you get drowned in all the numbers being thrown at you in lakhs of crores and trillions, I attempt to give readers a heterodox economics view drawing upon the tenets of Modern Money Theory (MMT) that allays many unnecessary fears about the fiscal deficit and instead shift focus to what should be the center of discussion.

Fiscal policy consists of two elements; government expenditure and taxes.  The first part of the budget is a statement of government expenditure decided upon at the beginning of the financial year.  Why does the government need to spend?  To achieve its political, economic and social objectives, the government must transfer real resources from the private sector to itself.  It does this by “spending” or literally “buying” goods and services from the private sector using its money or IOUs (I Owe You).  This leads to the most important question in MMT; why does the private sector accept the government’s money or IOUs?  To pay taxes; the private sector must discharge its tax obligations to the state only in the IOUs issued by the government or what we call as legal tender.  Taxes drive (state) money.  This is a critical feature of modern fiat money; the state does not need our money to spend.  Instead, we need the state’s money – that is created when it spends – to discharge our tax obligations to it.

But there is another crucial reason for imposition of taxes – controlling inflation[3] – which brings us to the second part of the budget. When the government spends its money into the economy, more of it will be available with the private sector which may drive up demand for goods and services, resulting in rising price levels or inflation.  To prevent this taxes are imposed on private sector entities in order to drain the economy of excess money injected through government spending.  But the government does not fix the amount of taxes that has to be paid by private agents.  For example, it cannot stipulate that a grocery store will have to pay Rs.100,000 in taxes every year.  What if sales of the grocery store falls drastically during the year?  The government therefore fixes the tax rate as a percentage of incomes, profit or sales.  Ideally income and corporate taxes are considered the most fair especially with progressive rates as well as non-distortionary (in terms of its low impact on relative prices).

Unfortunately, in a country like India where the tax base is abysmally narrow it becomes difficult to drain out government money from this small section of people without recourse to high tax rates – which then has a significant negative impact on incentives.  Instead, the government must resort to indirect taxes – like GST – which obviously has a wider tax base but is unfortunately regressive in its impact on the poor.  But that’s a compromise we have to live with perhaps partial offsetting by a lower tax rate on essential goods and services.

As the economy progresses through the year, the government’s policies as well as a multitude of other factors from private sector sentiments to international trends determines output produced, sales, incomes and profits that directly influence actual tax collections.  Unfortunately, when the economy does not perform as expected, tax collections turn out to be lower too while the deficit widens for any given amount of government expenditure undertaken.  This property of fiscal policy is called an “automatic stabilizer”; the deficit widens during times of poor economic growth and narrows when growth is strong.

At this point, let me digress briefly into what constitutes state money or its IOUs.  When the government buys goods and services from the private sector, your account in a commercial bank will be credited with a certain amount; these are simply tokens or numbers in the books of accounts of all stakeholders.  But the government does not do this transaction directly; instead, its banker (the central bank or the Reserve Bank of India) will credit “reserve money” into the account of the commercial bank which then credits your account with this sum.  This reserve money is the liability of the central bank or what it owes to the private sector.  If the private sector entity wants cash, the “reserve money” is printed on pieces of paper and delivered through the commercial bank so that it is easily exchangeable by private sector agents for transactions between themselves.  What about taxes?  Taxes must be remitted back to the government’s account at the central bank only with “reserve money” or “cash” (printed slips of reserve money).  When a private sector entity pays taxes the commercial bank debits its account and then transfers the same amount of reserve money (which it had earlier received when the government undertook spending) back to the central bank.  Government spending creates reserve money, taxes destroy the same. There is nothing physical about this money; it is essentially a grand bookkeeping system.

In the good ol’ days, the government could ask the central bank to credit its account with as much reserve money it wanted it to in exchange for government promises to pay back later or what is called, government securities or bonds.  The government/central bank would also sell these bonds to the public (and even promise to pay them interest on them) to mop up excess state money floating around in the private sector (untaxed spending) to prevent inflation.  These sale of bonds accumulated over time becomes the infamous and much feared public debt – what we, however, often fail to realize is that the other side of public debt is private sector (financial) assets.  Government bonds are the safest income yielding security that the private sector can hold – would we feel safe parking all our wealth in physical assets (land or gold) or in private sector financial assets (equity shares or commercial paper of companies)?  Obviously not; every individual would aspire that at least a part of his/her wealth be held in government securities or financial assets not backed by any physical asset (the latter could depreciate or at any time, turn bad).  In fact, the curtailing of public debt would force the private sector to save in private sector financial assets – the insecurity may even force the savings rate up and cause a contraction in consumption spending.

Does the government need to borrow in order to spend?  Obviously not; it could simply raise taxes or let inflation accelerate.  Moreover, the fact that the government does not need to borrow before it spends can easily be seen from the fact that bonds must be purchased from the government in exchange for reserve money only.  Just like taxes, spending (injection of reserve money) must precede bond issues (draining of reserve money).

Ever since the rise of neoliberal macroeconomics in the 1980s that sought to restrict the influence of the state in the free market system, fiscal policy was “proven” impotent.  The quantifiable target of government intrusion was the fiscal deficit and it had to be curtailed.  Governments were convinced (or perhaps forced to under the influence of structural adjustment programs of the IMF) that fiscal policy more than anything caused accelerating inflation that threw the free market system out of gear.  Low and stable inflation was made the center of macroeconomic policy so that market forces would propel the economy to full employment. For this, fiscal deficits had to be restricted and if not, “independent central banks” (under the charge of a professional economist) were given the power to set interest rates to mitigate the dangers of rising inflation from fiscal profligacy.  Rating agencies that imbibed and propagated this neoliberal worldview kept nation-states in-check and against deviating from this model.  After all, a de-rating could mean lower foreign exchange inflows (from FDI, ECB and FII flows) and a balance of payments crisis.

A further offshoot of neoliberal macroeconomics was pressure of governments to impose constrains on themselves – like the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM) Act of 2003 – whereby the government must not let the fiscal deficit rise above 3% of GDP and more importantly, it cannot engage in “deficit financing”.  This means that unlike the good ol’ days the government can no longer borrow or get an overdraft from the RBI but has instead to borrow in the market (from the private sector) before it spends. In other words, there must be sufficient money in the government’s account at the central bank before it signs cheques on the private sector.

Does this self-imposed constraint by the government really mean that the government cannot increase its expenditure if required?  Not really; a system[4] Primary Dealers (PDs) and Bank-PDs has been put in place wherein governments will be able to obtain the required amount through mandatory participation of these entities in the bond auctions.  The central bank, however, stands by to provide reserve money to PDs to meet their obligations.  In fact, it can be shown that “the end result is exactly the same as if the central bank had bought directly from the Treasury.” (Tymoigne 2014[5]).

So what I have attempted to show here is that the fiscal deficit or public debt target number is really not important; it cannot and must not be the objective of macroeconomic policy.  All this, however, does not mean there is no big deal on account of the widening fiscal deficit. In fact, there is a critical question that needs to be posed; what went wrong with government policies that brought down the growth rate sharply? And this even as the world is witnessing a kind of economic boom with robust growth, low unemployment and low inflation (although poor real wage growth).  Have the twin shocks of demonetization and GST implementation derailed the economy? Or is the unresolved NPA problem along with low private sector business sentiment suppressing growth?

Deflection from these questions into breaching of fiscal deficit target numbers is fraught with a greater danger – the imposition (with a little encouragement from rating agencies) of austerity measures – which as MMTers have long argued, is bound to take the country down a spiraling path – lower government spending, lower GDP growth, lower tax collections, widening fiscal deficits and therefore the need for even greater austerity!




[3] Taxes are also used to achieve other objectives; sectoral allocation of resources, curb negative externalities, redistribution of income and wealth, etc.  In this article, we consider the purely financial aspect of taxes.
[4] Master Circular – Operational Guidelines for Primary Dealers, Reserve Bank of India, July 1, 2015, https://www.rbi.org.in/scripts/BS_ViewMasCirculardetails.aspx?id=9841#8
[5] Éric Tymoigne, Modern Money Theory and Interrelations between the Treasury and the Central
Bank: The Case of the United States, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper # 788, March 2014, http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download;jsessionid=89DEA9B2158162AA06 B4840477ABF6D8?doi=10.1.1.640.4425&rep=rep1&type=pdf  

Sunday, October 2, 2016

My latest research from a heterodox macroeconomics perspective

Earlier this year, I had undertaken to carry out a few country studies from a heterodox macroeconomic perspective.  Three of them have now been published:
  1. China’s macroeconomic policy options: a sectoral financial balances approach,Studies in Business & Economics, 2016, 11(1): 152-163.

     
  2. Cracks in BRICs: a sectoral financial balances analysis and implications for macroeconomic policy, Theoretical and Applied Economics, 23(3), Autumn: 53-78.

     
  3. Can a country really go broke? Deconstructing Saudi Arabia’s macroeconomic crisis, Real World Economics Review, Issue 76, September 2016: 75-94.


    The above articles can be read at:



    http://Independent.academia.edu/SashiSivramkrishna
Looking forward to some critical comments.

Friday, June 12, 2015

The pressing need for a new perspective

Today's piece by Prof. Deepak Nayyar in the Livemint (12.06.2015) clearly summarizes the problem with neoliberal economics - although the work neoliberal was never mentioned.  At the core of neoliberalism is inflation targeting and its consequent implications for control of the fiscal deficit. These policies are strangling not just India but even countries like Greece which are unable to come out of depression.  Prof. Nayyar has highlighted the need for "to question and get away from a blind belief in any idea, for ideologies that turn into faith are dangerous."  Who can disagree?  But critiquing economics has always been countered with the question; what is the alternative?  I think here we need to turn to post-Keynesian economics ... and Modern Money Theory in particular.

Here's the link to Prof. Nayyar's article:

http://www.livemint.com/Opinion/DubsmSzgYLBp3Swu8TqPII/The-interest-rate-conundrum.html




Friday, May 22, 2015

The general drift of neoliberalism

Two headlines caught my attention today; from these we get a clear picture of the general drift of neoliberalism.   The Times of India (see link below) declared:

SOCIOECONOMICS: BIG TALK, TIGHT FIST
Funds cuts pinch edu & health schemes

Slashing the education budget and keeping the outlay on health static in Modi government's first Budget was seemingly based on the sound logic of the Finance Commission giving bigger share of taxes to states.

But three months later, harsh reality has sunk in. Mid-Day Meal (MDM) cooks, anganwadi workers and Mahila Samakhya workers have hit the streets and state governments are feeling the heat ….


The other headlines that was an interesting contrast to this was in the Livemint.

Industries call on Modi to spend Rs.1 trillion (Rs.100,000 crore) to boost economy

… At the top of India Inc.’s wish list are investments in infrastructure, simplification of rules for acquiring land and implementation of a proposed national sales tax. Executives say the government should take the lead in financing new roads and public projects to give the maximum boost to Asia’s third- biggest economy.

V.S. Parthasarathy, group chief financial officer at Mahindra and Mahindra Ltd, suggests Modi make a dramatic move by investing as much as Rs.1 trillion ($16 billion) on infrastructure in the next six months. That would provide the country with tangible assets, signal confidence in the future and inject cash that would cascade through the broader economy …


So is industry really against spending and deficits per se or does it prefer one kind of spending to another?  And the government?  Let’s be clear.



Friday, November 7, 2014

Here is some conventional macroeconomic rhetoric, extracted from an article in the Livemint of Friday, Nov.7, 2014.  MMTers can obviously see through the anxiety that is being raised here.


... “Given the sluggish growth of tax revenues in (the) first half of 2014/15, meeting the disinvestment target would be crucial to ensure that the fiscal deficit remains in line with the budgeted level,” said Aditi Nayar, an economist at ICRA, the Indian arm of rating agency Moody’s.

... Officials worry that a shortfall in proceeds from share sales and lower tax collections due to the weak economic recovery could force them to cut budgeted spending again.

... “The situation is not as bad as last year, but we may need expenditure cuts, maybe of Rs20,000-25,000 crore,” said the first source, adding there could be savings in capital spending as some ministries were unable to spend allocated funds.

Read more at: http://www.livemint.com/Politics/fUvEGpLThR9rVAtYvpDinN/Govt-may-fall-short-of-its-95-billion-privatisation-target.html?utm_source=copy

Saturday, October 25, 2014

German austerity: will the euro zone break up?

Anyone familiar with MMT would see the misery Germany is heading towards.  Even worse it will take with it the rest of Europe.  Excerpts below from an article that appeared in the Livemint today (25 October 2014) (http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/10/24/uk-eu-summit-idUKKCN0ID0VF20141024) clearly highlights the fears that many modern money theorists have been warning us about.  What is surprising is that there is no popular political voices coming from Germany that make an MMT argument against German austerity.

Stagnating euro zone seeks German shift
BY FRANCESCO GUARASCIO AND ROBIN EMMOTT

After the bloc's revival came to a halt in the second quarter, France and Italy want to shift course away from the spending cuts that marked the bloc's response to the 2009-2012 crisis Germany says debt discipline must continue.

Seated around a large oval table in the EU summit's red marble building, Merkel said no country with a national debt greater than its economic output should be borrowing more, diplomats said.

According to people in the room, Merkel said record low interest rates gave the euro zone "room to breathe" and that a mix of private investment, fiscal discipline and openness to fast-growing Asian economies was the way forward.
The debate is complicated by EU rules that seek to keep country's public finances in order and Germany's promise to balance its books next year for the first time since 1969.